The Voting Game in Game Theory and Its Impact on Elections
- professormattw
- Oct 23, 2024
- 5 min read
Game theory is a powerful mathematical framework used to analyze decision-making in competitive situations where outcomes depend on the choices of multiple participants. In elections, voters act as players, making strategic decisions to maximize their utility, or payoff, in terms of preferred policies, economic benefits, or social outcomes. This framework helps us understand why voters or coalitions sometimes vote in ways that don’t align with their best economic interests—particularly in cooperative voting games.

In cooperative voting games, groups of voters form coalitions to increase their influence. However, these coalitions can often result in individuals voting against their own interests, particularly when emotional or social issues overshadow rational, utility-maximizing decisions. Let’s break down the main concepts of game theory before diving into how it applies to voting and elections, including examples of how liberal fiscal policies, inflation, and taxes harm utility.
Main Elements of Game Theory in Simple Terms
Payoff (Utility Function):
The payoff in game theory represents the benefit a player receives from their decision. In elections, this could be economic benefits from a particular fiscal policy or social outcomes that align with the voter’s preferences. Mathematically, this is represented by the utility function—the higher the utility, the more satisfied the voter is with the outcome. For example, conservative fiscal policies like tax cuts often maximize utility for most voters by increasing disposable income and lowering the cost of living (Meltzer & Richard, 1981). Conversely, liberal fiscal policies, which tend to raise taxes and increase government spending, often reduce individual utility. As economists note, increased taxes generally reduce disposable income, hurting middle- and lower-income voters the most (Friedman, 2002).
Inflation also significantly erodes the average person’s utility. For instance, when inflation rates rise, purchasing power falls, and individuals can afford fewer goods and services. Recent studies highlight how inflation disproportionately affects the working class, whose wages do not rise in tandem with inflation, thus decreasing their overall utility (Blanchard & Gali, 2010). Liberal fiscal policies that prioritize increased spending often exacerbate inflation, leading to more economic instability for individuals.

Strategy:
A strategy in voting is the plan a voter follows to achieve the best possible outcome. However, many voters make decisions based on social issues rather than economic ones, even when the latter offers more utility. This is often seen in cases where voters prioritize liberal social policies, such as environmental regulations or social justice initiatives, which may emotionally resonate but offer little material benefit or even harm their financial well-being (Downs, 1957).
For example, voters who support strict environmental policies that raise energy costs may inadvertently hurt their own financial stability, as these policies can lead to higher fuel and electricity prices (Nordhaus, 2015). By focusing on social or moral issues, these voters neglect the economic impacts that directly affect their utility.
Nash Equilibrium:
A Nash Equilibrium occurs when no player can improve their payoff by changing their strategy, assuming others do not change theirs. In elections, coalitions can often result in equilibria that are suboptimal for individual voters. For example, a voter who supports both fiscal conservatism and social liberalism may join a coalition that promotes socially liberal policies at the expense of fiscal discipline, resulting in reduced personal utility through higher taxes or increased inflation (Mankiw, 2012). This suboptimal outcome becomes stable if all voters in the coalition choose not to defect, even though a better outcome could be achieved through different alliances.
Cooperative vs. Non-Cooperative Games:
In non-cooperative games, voters act independently, while in cooperative games, they form alliances or coalitions. In cooperative voting, groups of voters may sacrifice some preferences in favor of a collective goal. However, this often leads to unintended consequences, such as voting for policies that decrease individual utility in the long run.
The Voting Game in Elections: Voting Against One’s Own Interest

In cooperative voting, voters align with others to increase their collective influence. However, this often results in coalitions making decisions that go against individual interests. For example, many voters experience higher utility under conservative fiscal policies—such as lower taxes and reduced government spending—that promote economic growth and individual financial stability (Friedman, 2002). However, they may instead vote based on social issues, which offer little direct utility.
Liberal Fiscal Policies and Utility Loss
Consider voters who align with liberal coalitions based on social issues like equality or environmentalism. While these causes may be morally appealing, the fiscal policies tied to them, such as higher taxes and increased regulation, often lead to negative economic outcomes. For instance, higher taxes reduce disposable income, which decreases personal utility, particularly for middle- and lower-income voters (Mankiw, 2012).
Further, these liberal policies often contribute to inflation, which erodes purchasing power. Inflation occurs when government spending increases faster than economic output, causing prices to rise. Studies have shown that inflation has a disproportionately negative impact on the middle class, as wages typically lag behind rising prices, thus decreasing real income and utility (Blanchard & Gali, 2010). Liberal fiscal policies that prioritize high levels of government spending exacerbate this effect, leading to further disillusionment among voters.
Emergent Behavior and Chaos in Voting Systems
When cooperative voting leads to reduced utility, this can have broad systemic consequences. These effects can be understood through emergence theory and chaos theory.
1. Emergence Theory:
Emergence describes how complex collective behaviors arise from simpler individual actions. In voting, the behavior of coalitions or factions can lead to unexpected outcomes. For example, a coalition that supports social policies at the expense of fiscal responsibility may not realize the negative economic consequences until they materialize, such as rising inflation or higher living costs (Nordhaus, 2015). This emergent behavior results from the interaction of voters prioritizing social issues over fiscal ones, leading to unintended economic consequences.
2. Chaos Theory:
Chaos theory shows how small changes in voter behavior can lead to disproportionately large impacts. In voting systems, small shifts in strategy—such as a faction breaking away from a coalition—can lead to dramatically different election outcomes. For example, a slight change in voter turnout in key swing states can tip the balance in favor of a candidate whose policies promote inflation or higher taxes, leading to significant utility loss for the broader electorate (Lorenz, 1963).

Why This Matters for Elections
Understanding the dynamics of the voting game is crucial because it highlights the risks of strategic and cooperative voting. When groups vote against their own interest, it reduces individual utility, leading to dissatisfaction and potential disengagement from the political process. This can have ripple effects, such as lower voter turnout and unstable electoral outcomes.
By prioritizing social issues over fiscal policies that directly affect their financial well-being, voters may unwittingly support policies that reduce their utility through higher taxes, inflation, and economic instability (Mankiw, 2012). The result is a voting system that does not reflect the best interests of the electorate and can lead to systemic chaos.
Conclusion: The Complexities of Voting Games in Elections
In elections, voters must navigate a complex landscape of strategic decisions. Cooperative voting games, while useful for maximizing influence, can lead to unintended consequences that decrease utility. Liberal fiscal policies, inflation, and taxes are prime examples of how voters can end up supporting policies that harm their economic well-being, even when their utility would be higher under conservative fiscal policies.
By understanding game theory, voters can make more informed choices that align with their best interests, avoiding the pitfalls of emergent behavior and chaotic voting outcomes.
References:
• Blanchard, O., & Gali, J. (2010). Labor Markets and Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Model with Unemployment. American Economic Review.
• Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. Harper and Row.
• Friedman, M. (2002). Capitalism and Freedom. University of Chicago Press.
• Lorenz, E. N. (1963). Deterministic Nonperiodic Flow. Journal of the Atmospheric Sciences.
• Mankiw, N. G. (2012). Principles of Economics. Cengage Learning.
• Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A Rational Theory of the Size of Government. Journal of Political Economy.
• Nordhaus, W. (2015). The Climate Casino: Risk, Uncertainty, and Economics for a Warming World. Yale University Press.
Comments